Northern Economist 2.0

Wednesday, 17 January 2024

Reforming Thunder Bay City Council: The Journey Begins

 

It appears that Thunder Bay City Council has finally decided to get serious about looking at its size and composition with the move to appoint a six-member citizen committee that will lead a review process over the next year that might actually result in changes in time for the 2026 municipal election.  The committee will have a far-reaching mandate to explore the size of council, their status as full or part-time membership as well as the structure of the current at-large and ward hybrid model that has governed Thunder Bay municipal politics since the 1980s.  When Thunder Bay was created it 1970, it began with a mayor and 12 councillors elected evenly across four wards which was revised to seven wards in 1976 and then took its current form of seven ward and five at large councillors in 1985.

 

This is coming about nearly three years after a previous council began to explore the issue and which ultimately generated this post which concluded: “it would be better if more of an effort was made to commission an independent arm’s length panel to review the situation and present options to council.”  Well, a committee has finally been appointed by City Council and is made up of six members.  The committee is chaired by former councillor Rebecca Johnson and vice-chaired by another former councillor Cody Fraser as well as citizens Riley Burton, Wayne Bahlieda, Heather McLeod and Carlos Santander-Maturana. 

 

The committee will conduct a two-phase consultation with the public.  The first phase includes a survey to ascertain how the public engages and interacts with City Council and examining if they have a desire to see changes to the composition of council. Phase two will include discussion and consultation with the public on potential options that could result in changes to council composition and/or the ward boundaries.  The committee will then take all of this information and “provide a report to City council with recommended changes to the composition of council or the ward system next year”.

 

The wording on the City of Thunder Bay website seems to imply that there will be changes and the chair of the committee in a TBTNewswatch story seemed to say that she believed that this time there were going to be changes made.  Indeed, phase two already says it is about options for change even before phase one has ascertained a desire for change  This is somewhat disconcerting because it suggests that someone or somebody somewhere has already decided that changes will be made, and the only real question is what those changes might be.  When put alongside a less than transparent process for committee member selection that were apparently “carefully chosen” and a survey that requires registration, one begins to wonder if the result is already a foregone conclusion.  Of course, one should be charitable on an issue that has reared its head up numerous times over the years and has only finally resulted in a serious attempt to examine it.  Given the length of time it has taken to get to this point, I suppose one should simply be grateful a committee has been struck even if the process seems akin to foxes guarding the hen house.

 

It is fair to ask what possibly an economist could contribute to a debate on municipal governance?  However, barring the reality that economists are municipal citizens too, it remains that economists are fully capable of examining the costs and benefits of institutional arrangements and their evolution as well as public finance aspects.  It is not an incursion into new territory to be staked out but rather an extension of what many institutional economists and economic historians already do.   In the case of the size, structure, composition and representativeness of the current institutional arrangement, there needs to be a framework for the decision making as well as an examination of what issues need to be addressed with the change.

 

A change in the current arrangements of municipal council represents an institutional change or innovation and such changes should be made if the perceived net benefits of the new arrangement exceed the net benefits of the previous one plus the costs of transitioning to a new arrangement – both social and economic costs.  It requires in the end an analysis of the current system and its benefits and costs not just economically but in terms of effectiveness in democratic representation and decision making as well as community spirit and engagement. 

 

What is not functioning under the current arrangement?  What could be improved?  What are the advantages of the current system of seven ward and five at-large representatives plus a mayor and what are its drawbacks?  In other words, what exactly are we trying to fix or improve.  What is driving the need to make changes to city council?  For example, simply being unable to get a consensus on building a new turf facility is not a reason to change the decision-making mechanism. Similarly, rancorous meetings are also not a reason to reform city council if the debate results in things getting done or poor decisions avoided.

 

Much of the debate in the past has focused on issues like ward councillors being too focused on their wards and not seeing the “bigger picture” when it comes to city issues.  Other times, there have been concerns that at-large councillors by not being tied to a ward and its needs were somehow shirking their duties by picking and choosing what they wanted to focus on.  Indeed, Thunder Bay politics at the municipal level has occasionally seemed like council consisted of a mayor, five mayors in waiting and seven dwarf councillors left to do a lot of the heavy lifting on local issues.  On the other hand, one could also argue that having five at large councillors allowed for citizens to go beyond their immediate ward councillor when lobbying if they felt they had not had their issue addressed.

 

And the hybrid system itself with two types of councillors is rather unique – why is it that Thunder Bay cannot have either a system of all ward councillors or all at large councillors?  What was the original purpose of going to a hybrid model and have those reasons shifted?  Then, there is the issue of the total number of councillors given the population size as on a per capita basis Thunder Bay probably has more councillors than many other cities in Ontario.  Burlington, for example, with a population nearly double that of Thunder Bay, has six ward councillors plus a mayor.  Kingston, on the other hand, which is one and a half times Thunder Bay’s population, has a mayor representing “the city as a whole” and twelve district councillors.

 

Perhaps fewer councillors but all full-time rather than the current part-time might make for better decision making.  However, that would likely mean a higher stipend and part of the argument for reducing the size of council is a belief that somehow there are going to be cost savings.  If you are indeed looking at cost savings in municipal government, reducing the number and salaries of councillors is merely symbolic as the real savings lie elsewhere. On the other hand, one can argue that being a councillor is about community service and the money should not matter.

 

Would having all councillors as ward councillors make the council too parochial as each seeks only to look after neighborhood concerns?  Or will having all at-large councillors undermine the position of mayor as all councillors can claim to have a city-wide mandate from the electorate?  Indeed, if all the councillors are at large, why elect a separate mayor at all?  Make the mayor the at-large councillor with the most votes.  Or, if we move to an all-at-large approach, will only high-profile individuals and financially better off individuals being able to run for council given that ward races can favour ward residents with close neighborhood ties while city wide campaigns are more expensive to mount? 

 

And all of this of course is intertwined with the issue about whether we need to or should redesign our ward system given the current imbalances in population across wards as populations in the city have shifted.  Should we go to eight or ten numbered as opposed to named wards with approximately equivalent populations, as well as a mayor?  Should the councillors be all at-large or all ward based or some new type of hybrid?  What should the borders of the new wards be?  Will changing the number of wards and councillors as well as redesigning borders lead to better democratic accountability?  More citizen involvement? And on top of all of this – do we want a first past the post system electing our councillors?  Ranked or weighted ballots – especially for at-large candidates?

 

 


 

As mentioned before, all of this is really not new territory for an economist.  Institutions and their quality are fundamental to successfully functioning economies.  Has Thunder Bay been hurt economically by its current municipal institutions? Indeed, one could in a moment of introspection go further and ask if amalgamation was responsible for the economic slowdown after 1970 given a monopoly one-city government replaced what were a set of competitive municipalities.  There can be a lot at stake here as change for the sake of change without understanding the reasons for change as well as the long-term ramifications can leave us worse off.  Borrowing from the words of our outgoing City Manager, if you “don’t know what you don’t know”, then how can you know that what you are doing is the best decision possible?  The committee indeed has its work cut out for it and one hopes that they are independently minded enough to be able to know what questions to ask, when to ask them and more importantly, when to suggest to do something and when to do nothing.

Friday, 15 October 2021

Ontario’s Pandemic: The Beginning of the End or the End of the Beginning?

 

The last few weeks have seen a major improvement in Ontario’s daily COVID-19 case account.  The fourth wave seems to have peaked at just under 1,000 daily cases several weeks ago and for the last seven days has averaged under 500 daily cases (See Figure).  This is at the bottom of the scenarios that were envisaged just a short while ago as the fourth wave picked up steam and this may indeed be the beginning of the end of the pandemic in Ontario. At the same time, we may simply be embarking on a new post-pandemic era characterized by intermittent ebbs and flows of infection and a long-term change in how things are done.  In the end, it has been a remarkable learning process.

 


 

We appear to owe this new diminished phase of the pandemic partly to continued public restrictions with respect to the wearing of masks in public places and the high rates of vaccination.   The prolonged restrictions and phased in reopening over the summer has also been wise given the experience of Alberta and Saskatchewan with the Delta variant.  The high rates of vaccination in the province have been having their desired effects and the onset of the vaccine passport system has encouraged more hold backs to go and get vaccinated.  Yet, there are bumps.  The fact that the new QR code vaccine passport many can download for the first time today requires iOS 15 - for many of us a new iPhone - means a lot of us are not going to be conveniently loading it into our Apple Wallets.

 

And while the provincial government is apparently planning to announce a further relaxation next week in pandemic restrictions dealing with capacities in assorted public venues at the same time, it is announcing new restrictions reflecting slower progress in other areas.  The easing of pandemic measures will include ending capacity limits in all locations where proof-of-vaccination requirements are in place, such as restaurants, bars and gyms, a senior official in Ford's government said on Wednesday.  To its credit, it is going to retain the requirement for masking in public spaces.  Moreover, future outbreaks will apparently be met with more local response as opposed to province wide one size fits all provincial lock downs though my guess is that is more aspirational given the heavy handed tendency towards centralization of policy at Queen’s Park.

 

At the same time, it has been recently announced that long-term care homes will be instituting testing for staff and visitors whether doubly vaccinated or not at the same time that it is mandating vaccines for all long-term care home staff by November 15th.  While this continued testing has been out forth as “random” testing to provide early detection of breakthrough cases, some evidence to date suggests that Ontario LTC homes will be interpreting it as weekly testing suggesting that things will not be going back to normal for some time. Calling it "random" may be government political word massage to make visitors to LTC homes think it is not going to be formalized but it remains that the Oxford Dictionary defines random as: "done, chosen, etc. without somebody deciding in advance what is going to happen, or without any regular pattern" and not something done on a weekly basis.

 

The fact that testing is going to be used on doubly vaccinated individuals (who granted can still transmit the virus) while some hospitals have announced that visitors (to be clear not patients) will require double vaccination to get in to see their loved ones suggests that the real elephant in the room is still the high proportion of not vaccinated people in Ontario – for which a lot of other vaccinated people will continue to pay the price.  It remains that as of today only 73 percent of all people in Ontario are fully vaccinated.  And in long-term care homes, as of the latest figures for end of August, more than half of homes had less than 90 percent of their staff doubly vaccinated.

 

So, practice and implementation continue to lag science and evidence though the other revealing result of this pandemic has been how much public health, epidemiology and infectious disease science is a lot more like economic science than they would care to admit.  When it comes to scientific expertise, the pandemic has revealed that we are all economists now. Economists have been the butt of jokes for years about how their economic forecasts always seemed off the mark and yet during the pandemic, epidemiologists, bio-statisticians, and other assorted medical experts, have joined the ranks of economists and weather forecasters – not just in the range of forecasts provided but by the constantly shifting advice.   One does not have to think that far back to recall debates and discussion over whether to close border or wait, aerosol transmission or not aerosol, masks are effective or not effective, take AstraZeneca, don’t take AstraZeneca, etc.

 

In the end, this will hopefully be a humbling experience for science that will improve it.  Economic science, like the other sciences is evidence based and empirical with theoretical frameworks driving the analysis.  Facts are indeed facts but interpretation of the facts via theory and explanation is open to debate, consensus only evolves over time, and most importantly:  decision and policy making based on the evidence and the conclusions drawn from the evidence in the end is not done by the scientists but by politicians and civil servants who have agendas and constraints of their own not least of which is public reception and compliance.  The decisions in the end have been much more coloured by the art of the possible than many would have liked. We are indeed at an end but the drama continues.